Sightline: Climate pricing 101
The Seattle-based Sightline Institute offers this tidy and accessible overview of carbon taxes versus cap-and-trade (in two flavours), with some scoring as to who supports what. Canada’s New Harperment supports none of the options below, and Harper has been on the international stage telling everyone else to be “flexible”.
Climate Pricing 101
A primer on cap and trade, carbon taxes, and other exciting ways to slash our greenhouse gas emissions.
A Sightline work-in-progress: a primer on cap and trade, carbon taxes, and other exciting ways to slash our greenhouse gas emissions. Part of our climate policy research project.
(Last updated on September 21, 2007)
Cap & Trade (with Auctioning)
Description: The government sets a firm cap on total annual CO2 emissions. Major emitters, such as utilities or refineries, must purchase credits for their emissions in regularly scheduled auctions. Emitters with low-cost reduction options have an incentive to reduce their emissions and sell any excess credits they may have purchased. On the other hand, emitters with higher-cost emissions reduction choices will buy additional credits rather than reducing their emissions.
Pros:
- Real reductions: The cap, which will shrink over time, guarantees that specific emissions reductions targets will be met.
- Revenue source: Auction revenue can be used to ease the burden on those wilth lower incomes (thereby reducing or eliminating the prgoram’s regressivity), reduce the program’s compliance costs, or finance more rapid emissions reductions.
- Low-cost reductions: Typically, the cheapest and easiest reductions will be made first. Where reducing emissions is cheaper than the cost of the permits, emitters will choose to make reductions in their emissions.
Cons:
- Price volatility: Some market-based emissions trading systems have experienced large price swings.
- Complexity and delay – Complex new rules could foster delay, political wrangling among special interests, and difficulties with enforcement.
- Geographic scope – The program’s market efficiencies are probably better realized at a regional or national level, such as the Western Climate Initiative.
Supporters and prospects: The European Union plans to auction more allowances. The Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative among northeastern states will auction at least 25 percent of its allowances; Massachusetts, among others states, plans to auction 100 percent of their credits. Hydro and nuclear utilities may support cap and auction. Support from Natural Resources Defense Council, Congressional Budget Office, economist Larry Goulder (Stanford University), among many others. Most environmental groups and many economists support cap and auction.
Cap & Trade (with Grandfathering)
Description: As with the auctioning system, above, the government sets a firm cap on total annual CO2 emissions. In a grandfathering system the government then awards or allocated emissions credits for free to emitters based on their historical or expected. emissions. The credits can be used by owner, or sold to other emitters. The financial incentives for trading credits works the same as in cap and auction, outlined above. (Note there there is not necessarily a bright line between the auction and grandfathering flavors of cap and trade; many current proposals are a hybrid.)
Pros:
- Real reductions: The cap, which will shrink over time, guarantees that specific emissions reductions targets will be met.
- Familiar and tested: Grandfathered cap and trade systems are underway for sulfur dioxide and nitrogen oxides in the U.S, and CO2 in the European Union. The U.S sulfur dioxide program has been very successful.
- Competitive edge: Granting emissions credits for free can help industries remain competitive with companies in regions without CO2 caps.
- Smooth transition: Existing major emitters don’t have to scramble to buy credits.
- Low-cost reductions: Typically, the cheapest and easiest reductions will be made first. Where reducing emissions is cheaper than the tradeable value of the permits, emitters will choose to make reductions in their emissions.
Cons:
- Price volatility: Some market-based emissions trading systems have experienced huge price swings as a result of over-allocating allowances.
- Complexity and delay: Complex new rules could foster delay, political wrangling among special interests, and difficulties with enforcement.
- Geographic scope: The program’s market efficiencies are probably better realized at a regional or national level, such as the Western Climate Initiative.
- Windfall profits: Granting free credits means conferring a windfall to polluters (because the credits are a valuable fungible commodity).
- Inherently regressive: A grandfathered system provides no revenue to help cushion the program’s effects on the poor and middle class, or to finance other objectives to support reducing emissions.
Supporters and prospects: The European Union has a grandfathered cap and trade system. The Northeast Regional Greenhouse Gas Initiative includes at least some grandfathering. Many proposed cap-and-trade bills include at least partial grandfathering. The U.S Climate Action Partnership (British Petroleum, General Motors, General Electric, Environmental Defense, World Resources Institute, and many others) favors grandfathering.
Carbon Tax
Description: Government levies a fee on greenhouse gas emissions, based on the amount of CO2, or equivalent, is emitted. The fee can be phased in, ratcheted up to improve effectiveness, or reduced as needed.
Pros
- Predictable costs: Relatively stable price signal can help businesses and consumers plan energy spending and provide greater certainty for those efficiency investments that have large up-front costs.
- Fast implementation: Rules are fairly straightforward, and can be implemented using existing tax collection and enforcement infrastructure.
- Full coverage: An “upstream tax†– one that’s levied where fuels enter the economy at the mine, wellhead, tanker or pipeline — could cover 90 percent of CO2 emissions from fossil fuels.
- Revenue source: As with cap and auction, the program revenue (the tax receipts) could be used to ease burdens on poor and middle class, offset unpopular taxes, reduce compliance costs, finance rapid reductions, or aid industry.
Cons
- No guarantees: Emissions may not fall if people are willing to pay higher costs, as has been the case with gasoline and diesel. Note, however, that even a modest tax on CO2 tax is likely to discourage coal-fired power.
- The “T Wordâ€: Taxes are thought to be toxic to voters, and could be difficult to maintain taxes or to ratchet them upward if further emissions reductions are needed.
Supporters and prospects: Sweden, Norway, Finland, Demark, the Netherlands and, more recently, Quebec levy carbon taxes. Many economists, such as William Nordhaus (Yale University), Charles Komanoff (Carbon Tax Center), Kenneth Green (American Enterprise Institute), Ian Parry (Resources For the Future), and Greg Mankiw (Harvard University), favor carbon taxes. See the Carbon Tax Center for other supporters.