Marc’s testimony to the Senate on population aging and health care

I was a testator (if I was a woman I’d be a testatrix!) to the Senate Special Committee on Aging today, along with national treasure, Bob Evans, a couple reps from the Canadian Institute on Health Information, and UNB’s Joe Ruggeri. We all pretty much agreed that aging is not the issue it is made out to be. As Evans says, the intellectual debate is over, but the notion that we are headed over a cliff due to the greying of Canada is a zombie that inhabits our media.

And as timing would have it, the Fraser Institute for the Economically Insane just released its 2007 “sky is falling” health care report today. The conclusion is hardly a shocker: the Fraser finds once again that public health care is unsustainable.

Below is my testimony, which is largely based on my recent study for CCPA.

Testimony to the Senate Special Committee on Aging
December 3, 2007

Thanks to the Senate for having me here by videoconference today to speak to the issue of population aging and the public health care system. I wrote a report on this issue that was released in September by the CCPA, and I believe you have copies.

What I did in the report was to isolate the different cost drivers in the public health care system. I looked back to 1975 for a historical overview of how those factors have affected costs, then projected forward to 2056 based on Statistics Canada’s population forecasts and the average health care inflation rate over the past decade.

My finding reinforces those of past studies of the issue: Population aging, in and of itself, is but a small contributor to rising cost pressures in the health care system. Based on current projections there is little to suggest a demographic time-bomb about to go off.

The main cost drivers, in addition to an aging population, are population growth and health care specific inflation. Put these three together and one can determine a minimum amount of annual public spending increase necessary to maintain the existing level of services while accommodating a larger and older population.

On this basis, public health care spending must increase by 4.4% per year in the near term in order to maintain a sustainable level of services (by the 2030s the rate slows as population pressures ease). Population aging alone requires about 1% per year in additional public expenditures. So, while the demographic changes over a quarter-century due to aging are indeed profound, this change happens relatively slowly and the associated annual increase is actually less than either population growth or inflation.

What really matters for sustainability is the share of public health care spending relative to our GDP. That is, as long as nominal GDP growth averages 4.4% per year or more, there is no sustainability problem. If future economic growth rates are consistent with those over the past decade (average of 5.6%) or two (average of 5.4%), they will actually lead to public health care expenditures falling as a share of GDP.

In my paper I estimate public health care spending relative to GDP for a few scenarios of nominal GDP growth. Even if GDP growth was to slow to 4% per year (a level that is well below historical trends) existing levels of service could be maintained with only a small increase in health care expenditures relative to GDP over the next three decades. Public health care expenditures would rise to 8.4% of GDP by 2038, when they hit their peak. After this, as population pressures ease, they fall back to 7.6% by 2056.

One thing I have not mentioned yet but that is essential in thinking about health care spending is the enrichment or expansion of public health care services over time. My study tries to distinguish between annual spending increases required to maintain the same level of services from additional spending that expands the suite of health care services available under the public umbrella.

The issue of enrichment is historically significant. The average Canadian receives more than one and a half times more health care services as his or her equivalent three decades ago. So one important reason why health care spending is higher today is that we provide more services, including things like long-term care and home care, more expansive drug coverage, but also new surgical techniques, and new diagnostic technologies.

In fact, the real challenge for financing the health care system is advances in these technologies – the essentially unlimited potential to expand the realm of the possible. For example, compared to 1990/91, an 80-year-old in BC today is twice as likely to have a knee replacement, cataract surgery, or coronary bypass.

Highly technologically-intensive, end-of-life care poses some particularly challenging ethical dilemmas in cases where quality of life or health status is not ameliorated despite great cost. In fact, according to some important studies, it is not so much the rise in costs as one ages, as it is the expenditures made in one’s final year of life irrespective of age.

In my modeling, as long as economic growth rates are consistent with those in the past, if we maintain the current level of public health care spending to GDP, there is still room left over to accommodate new technological advances or to expand the system in other ways. But this is not unlimited, and at some point, if we want more technology, or expansion of other services, then we will have to pay a greater share of our income in order to have it. And that means being more rigorous about the costs and benefits of different technologies through health technology assessments, as recommended by the Romanow report.

By the numbers, the historical average enrichment rate is just under 2% per year over the 1975 to 2006 period. In my paper, I find that a 1% annual enrichment rate would require an increase in public health care expenditures from 7.4% of GDP in 2006 to a peak of 8.5% by 2038, but then falling back to 7.7% by 2056. This would, however, enable the average Canadian to enjoy 63% more health care services by 2056.

To conclude, it is a myth that an aging population will render the public health care system unsustainable. The good news is that the challenges facing public health care are not demographic factors beyond our control, but technological issues that, while profound, are suitable to a public process that is well within our control. In other words, like every other policy area, we need to make choices, and to do that we need a healthy democratic debate.

2 comments

  • “the notion that we are headed over a cliff due to the greying of Canada is a zombie that inhabits our media.”

    I have to wonder if that lot are getting it from the same sources as those down south are getting it from:

    http://www.leftbusinessobserver.com/AntisocInsec.html

  • I’m pretty sure the “ethically challenging” end-of-life issues will turn into mandated “economically challenging” budget issues. If there’s on thing I’ve learned from studying environmental policy it’s that boomers won’t shortchange themselves.

    Canadians started making babies one year after WWII ended thx to late payments. The average male life expectancy is about 66yrs for those born around then. People incur about 1/2 their health costs in their last year of life (I think, maybe I’m screwing this up and it is really last 5 years). IDK what the life expectancy curve looks like for males born in 1947, but somewhere between around 2011-2012, health care costs should really start to trend up.
    Every time I mention health, I plug Medonyx’s gelFAST (also Sprixx offers a similiar device), a pager-like alcohol dispensor device nurses and doctors could wear to reduce hospital nosocomial staph infection rates (5-10% of a hospital’s expenses) by 1/2. Makes a great antipandemic tool too.
    I’ve also read a newspaper blurb about CHAT, a California University study that telemarketed sedentary people automated messages to exercise. It worked, the people receiving messages exercised 40 mins/week longer than the 119 min/week couch potatoes. Provincial Healthcare crowns in Canada and their counterparts globally in fast food nations, need to start spamming their citizens ASAP.

    Also, some public health agency in Canada wants a metric for estimating productivity of health dollars as measured by life expectancy, I read in a newspaper blurb.
    It makes more sense to measure by an individual’s productivity (whether costed by GDP, or uncosted by GDP such as volunteering or contributing to a household economy) by aggregate lifetime earnings (including uncosted social capital) than by life expectancy for the simple reason health care expenditures come out of tax dollars (even in the uncosted case, a senior who is given a hip-replacement and can babysit, facilitates an unskilled parent’s entry to the workforce).

    Too bad a crap Canadian environment platform exists or me and many other researchers would spend more time studying aging boomer-issues. Prosthetics that boomers need to age gracefully (hearing aids, future broken-bones resistant textiles), could be given GST-exempt status, but now that the GST is 5% maybe that isn’t wise since surpluses are needed to fund future bright budget ideas (as opposed to luxury goods).

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *